ec537 microeconomic theory for research students part ii
play

EC537 Microeconomic Theory for Research Students, Part II: Lecture 1 - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

EC537 Microeconomic Theory for Research Students, Part II: Lecture 1 Leonardo Felli CLM.G.4 8 November 2011 Course Outline Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1: Contracts what are they? The Coase Theorem, Hidden Information, Bilateral trading.


  1. EC537 Microeconomic Theory for Research Students, Part II: Lecture 1 Leonardo Felli CLM.G.4 8 November 2011

  2. Course Outline Topics in Contract Theory Lecture 1: Contracts what are they? The Coase Theorem, Hidden Information, Bilateral trading. Lecture 2: Hidden Action, Multi-Tasking, Informed Principal, Intertemporal Incentives. Lecture 3: Implementation and the Foundations of Contracting with Unverifiable Information. Lecture 4: Transaction Costs. Lecture 5: Hold-Up Problem, Specific Investments and Competition. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC537 Microeconomic Theory for Research Students, Part II: Lecture 1 8 November 2011 2 / 79

  3. Admin My coordinates: S.478, x7525, lfelli@econ.lse.ac.uk PA: Elizabeth Mirhady, S.686, e.mirhady@lse.ac.uk. Office Hours: Wednesday 3:30-4:30 p.m. or by appointment (e-mail lfelli@econ.lse.ac.uk). Course Material: available at: http://econ.lse.ac.uk/staff/lfelli/teaching Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC537 Microeconomic Theory for Research Students, Part II: Lecture 1 8 November 2011 3 / 79

  4. References: Contract Theory Oliver Hart, Firms Contracts and Financial Structure , Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1995. Jean-Jacques Laffont and David Martimort, The Theory of Inncentives: The Principal-Agent Model , Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press, 2002. Patrick Bolton and Mathias Dewatripont, Contract Theory , Cambridge: M.I.T. Press, 2004. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC537 Microeconomic Theory for Research Students, Part II: Lecture 1 8 November 2011 4 / 79

  5. The Contract The first natural question that needs to be answered is: What is a contract? Definition A contract is the ruling of an economic transaction: the description of the performance that the contracting parties agree to complete at a (possibly future) date. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC537 Microeconomic Theory for Research Students, Part II: Lecture 1 8 November 2011 5 / 79

  6. Example: a contract for the purchase of a specific item, say a meal. It specifies: the restaurant’s performance (number of courses, quality of food, cooking details, etc. . . ), the customer’s performance (payment in full upon completion). Contracts involve not only the contracting parties, but also outsiders (enforcing authority: Court or Enforcer). Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC537 Microeconomic Theory for Research Students, Part II: Lecture 1 8 November 2011 6 / 79

  7. We distinguish between implicit and explicit contracts. A contract is implicit or self-enforcing whenever the environment in which the contracting parties operate corresponds to the extensive form of a game whose (unique) subgame perfect Nash equilibrium (PBE) exactly corresponds to the outcome the parties would like to implement. If you believe in SPE or PBE then there is no need for explicit communication. The two rational individuals will behave in the way required. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC537 Microeconomic Theory for Research Students, Part II: Lecture 1 8 November 2011 7 / 79

  8. If the outcome the parties would like to implement is not the subgame perfect Nash equilibrium of the environment in which they operate the parties might want to modify the environment. This is accomplished through an explicit contract. An explicit contract is a commitment device requiring: an explicit agreement between the parties, the intervention of a third party: the enforcer . Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC537 Microeconomic Theory for Research Students, Part II: Lecture 1 8 November 2011 8 / 79

  9. The role of the enforcer is to force the parties to behave in a way that differs from the one that would arise in the absence of any agreement. An explicit contract therefore specifies a new extensive form corresponding to a new game for the parties. The usual way for the enforcer to guarantee that the parties operate in this new environment is by modifying the parties’ payoffs , when necessary. By agreeing to bring in an enforcer in the game the parties commit to play a game that differs from the initial one they were in. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC537 Microeconomic Theory for Research Students, Part II: Lecture 1 8 November 2011 9 / 79

  10. To see how the presence of an enforcer may work consider the following example: (Kreps, 1984) A buyer B and a seller S wish to trade an indivisible item at date 1. The buyer’s valuation: v , The seller’s delivery cost: c . Let v > c In other words, trade is socially efficient . Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC537 Microeconomic Theory for Research Students, Part II: Lecture 1 8 November 2011 10 / 79

  11. Let p be a reasonable price level (we abstract for the moment from bargaining) such that: v > p > c . B ’s and S ’s situation may be described by the following normal form: deliver not deliver pay p v − p , p − c − p , p not pay p v , − c 0 , 0 Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC537 Microeconomic Theory for Research Students, Part II: Lecture 1 8 November 2011 11 / 79

  12. The unique Nash equilibrium (dominant solvable) is: ( B does not pay , S does not deliver) . This is clearly an inefficient outcome: no trade. The situation does not change if any of the following two extensive forms are played. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC537 Microeconomic Theory for Research Students, Part II: Lecture 1 8 November 2011 12 / 79

  13. The unique SPE of the following game is: { B does not pay , S does not deliver at both nodes } . B ❜ � ❅ � ❅ pay p not pay p � ❅ � ❅ � ❅ S S � ❅ q q ☞ ▲ ☞ ▲ ☞ ▲ ☞ ▲ ☞ ▲ ☞ ▲ deliver not deliver not ☞ ▲ ☞ ▲ deliver deliver ☞ ▲ ☞ ▲ ☞ ▲ ☞ ▲ ☞ ▲ ☞ ▲ ☞ ▲ ☞ ▲ q q q q ( v − p , p − c ) ( − p , p ) ( v , − c ) (0 , 0) Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC537 Microeconomic Theory for Research Students, Part II: Lecture 1 8 November 2011 13 / 79

  14. The unique SPE of the following game is: { S does not deliver , B does not pay at both nodes , } . S ❜ � ❅ � ❅ deliver not deliver � ❅ � ❅ � ❅ B B � ❅ q q ☞ ▲ ☞ ▲ ☞ ▲ ☞ ▲ ☞ ▲ ☞ ▲ pay p pay p not not ☞ ▲ ☞ ▲ pay p pay p ☞ ▲ ☞ ▲ ☞ ▲ ☞ ▲ ☞ ▲ ☞ ▲ ☞ ▲ ☞ ▲ q q q q ( p − c , v − p ) ( − c , v ) ( p , − p ) (0 , 0) Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC537 Microeconomic Theory for Research Students, Part II: Lecture 1 8 November 2011 14 / 79

  15. Solution: to this inefficiency is an explicit contract enforced by a third party (enforcer). It specifies: the payment p that B is supposed to make contingent on S delivering the item, the punishment F B > p (implicit in the legal system) imposed by the enforcer on B in the event that S delivers and B does not pay, the punishment F S > c (implicit in the legal system) imposed by the enforcer on S in the event that B pays but S does not deliver. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC537 Microeconomic Theory for Research Students, Part II: Lecture 1 8 November 2011 15 / 79

  16. In this case the normal form describing the contracting parties problem once the contract is in place is: deliver not deliver pay p v − p , p − c F S − p , p − F S not pay p v − F B , F B − c 0 , 0 The unique Nash equilibrium is now: ( B pays p , S delivers) . This particular contract is budget balanced off-the-equilibrium-path (renegotiation proof) . The latter property does not always hold. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC537 Microeconomic Theory for Research Students, Part II: Lecture 1 8 November 2011 16 / 79

  17. Consider now an environment in which when a party goes to the enforcer (goes to court) detection is costly ( κ ) and is successful only with probability π . The payoffs associated with (not pay p , deliver) are: v − π ( F B + κ ) , π F B − (1 − π ) κ − c The payoffs associated with (pay p , not deliver) are: π F S − (1 − π ) κ − p , p − π ( F S + κ ) Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC537 Microeconomic Theory for Research Students, Part II: Lecture 1 8 November 2011 17 / 79

  18. Notice that as deterrence goes: the detection probability (policing, monitoring) π and the size of the punishment, F B and F S , are substitutes (Becker 1968). The game, below, assumes that the enforcer’s costs κ are paid by the loosing party (British system): deliver not deliver π F S − (1 − π ) κ − p , pay p v − p , p − c p − π ( F S + κ ) v − π ( F B + κ ) , not pay p 0 , 0 π F B − (1 − π ) κ − c If court’s costs κ are too high the game has multiple Nash equilibria: (pay p , deliver) and (not pay p , not deliver). Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC537 Microeconomic Theory for Research Students, Part II: Lecture 1 8 November 2011 18 / 79

  19. This example clearly shows the need for an enforcement mechanism . This mechanism may be due to: the parties being involved in a repeated relationship relationship/implicit contracting, (multiplicity might be a problem). the presence of a legal system that enforces the parties agreement (explicit contracting) . Notice that according to this interpretation the enforcer is essentially a commitment device available to the parties that can be used when the parties agree to call it in. Leonardo Felli (LSE) EC537 Microeconomic Theory for Research Students, Part II: Lecture 1 8 November 2011 19 / 79

Download Presentation
Download Policy: The content available on the website is offered to you 'AS IS' for your personal information and use only. It cannot be commercialized, licensed, or distributed on other websites without prior consent from the author. To download a presentation, simply click this link. If you encounter any difficulties during the download process, it's possible that the publisher has removed the file from their server.

Recommend


More recommend